朋的博客

MySQL资料,Java技术,管理思想,博弈论,Ajax,XP极限编程,H.264,HEVC,HDR
随笔 - 86, 文章 - 59, 评论 - 1069, 引用 - 0
数据加载中……

投资组合和财富(最近的阅读论文)

2004组合投资与财富状况

Journal of Financial Economics
Volume 72, Issue 3 , June 2004, Pages 457-484

Portfolio choice and health status*1

Abstract

This paper analyzes the role health status plays in household portfolio decisions using data from the Health and Retirement Study. The results indicate that health is a significant predictor of both the probability of owning different types of financial assets and the share of financial wealth held in each asset category. Households in poor health are less likely to hold risky financial assets, other things (including the level of total wealth) being the same. Poor health is associated with a smaller share of financial wealth held in risky assets and a larger share in safe assets. We find no evidence that the relationship between health status and portfolio allocation is driven by "third variables" that simultaneously affect health and financial decisions. Further, the relationship between health status and portfolio choice does not appear to operate through the effect of poor health on individuals’ attitudes toward risk, their planning horizons, or their health insurance status.

Author Keywords: Portfolio; Health; Risk

1. Introduction

Economists have long realized the importance of understanding individual portfolio choice. Recent empirical work on individual portfolio choice focuses on a number of important questions, including the impacts of bequest motives (Hurd, 2002), undiversifiable human capital risk ( Heaton and Lucas, 2000), and the differential tax treatment of income generated by various assets ( Poterba, 2001).

The role of health status receives little attention. While several studies show that health affects total wealth accumulation (Smith, 1999; Venti and Wise, 2000; Wu, 2003), there is much less research on how health influences the allocation of that wealth to various assets. Edwards (2002) develops a theoretical model in which health risk determines portfolio shares through its effect on risk aversion. One can imagine other channels through which health could affect portfolio composition. Poor health can influence an individual's marginal utility of consumption, the degree of risk aversion, rate of time preference, and the variability of her labor income, all of which could affect portfolio composition. Because health tends to deteriorate with age and older people control a disproportionate amount of total wealth, it seems particularly pressing to understand how poor health affects portfolio allocation decisions.

The purpose of this paper is to investigate whether differences in health status help explain differences in individual portfolio composition, ceteris paribus. We examine how health status relates to both the probability that a household holds a particular type of asset in its portfolio and the share of financial wealth held in each asset category. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews previous empirical work on household portfolio choice. Section 3 discusses the empirical strategy and describes the data. In 4 and 5 we examine the impact of health status on the choice of assets and on the proportion of financial wealth held in the various assets, respectively. We find that health effects are present in both sets of decisions. In particular, households in poor health are less likely to hold all classes of financial assets, other things (including the level of total wealth) being the same. Further, poor health is associated with a larger share of financial wealth held in safe assets and a smaller share in other classes of assets. Section 6 concludes with a summary and suggestions for future research.

2. Previous literature

A rich theoretical literature demonstrates how portfolio decisions depend on factors such as risk aversion and investment opportunities.1 Early contributions analyzed static models in which an investor selects the portfolio that maximizes expected utility given total wealth and the risk-return pattern of available assets (Tobin, 1958; Mossin, 1968). More recent research has moved to a dynamic framework in which one's portfolio is selected to maximize expected lifetime utility. Important issues include the role of incomplete portfolios ( King and Leape, 1998), human capital uncertainty ( Heaton and Lucas, 1997), the ability to substitute labor income for asset income ( Bodie et al., 1992), and uncertain time horizons ( Foldes, 2000).

The empirical literature on portfolio choice seeks to find observable variables that explain cross-sectional variation in portfolio behavior. Typically, the covariates used include resources available to the household (total wealth and income) as well as demographic characteristics (age, race, gender, marital status). Such variables are generally statistically significant and quantitatively important in regressions explaining portfolio behavior, both in US and European data. (Examples include: Bertaut and Starr-McCluer, 2002; Carroll, 2002; Guiso et al., 2002).

Most empirical work in this area addresses two distinct but related questions regarding portfolio choice. First, does the individual or household hold a positive amount of a given asset at all? Second, what proportion of the total portfolio is held in each asset? This approach of estimating reduced-form models for ownership probabilities and for portfolio shares has served as a fruitful starting point for analyzing a number of issues relating to portfolio allocation. Examples include Poterba and Samwick (2003), who include marginal tax rates to study the impact of the federal income tax; Heaton and Lucas (2000), who use a measure of the variability of labor income to investigate whether the riskiness of human capital affects the demand for financial assets; and Edwards (2002), who includes an attitudinal variable (the individual's subjective probability that health will limit work activity over the next decade)—to examine whether health risk affects portfolio choice. We adopt the same basic approach to analyze the effect of health status on portfolio composition.

3. Data and empirical strategy

We use data from four waves of the Health and Retirement Study (HRS). The HRS is a nationally representative panel that follows across time approximately 7,000 households with a primary respondent between the ages of 51 and 61 during the first year of the survey. The first wave of the study was conducted in 1992, so the primary respondents represent cohorts born between 1931 to 1941. The next three waves of the survey were collected in 1994, 1996, and 1998. While this sample is clearly not representative of the entire age distribution of households, Poterba (1994, p. 2) and others show that net worth is highly concentrated among older households. Further, tabulations from the 1998 Survey of Consumer Finances indicate that households headed by individuals between the ages of 51 and 67 own about 44% of the equity in the economy. Hence, as suggested above, this is an important group to study in the context of portfolio composition issues.

The survey includes detailed information on health, cognitive status, and a variety of economic and demographic variables. Of particular interest for our analysis is that the HRS provides information on each household's holdings of a quite comprehensive set of financial assets including checking, savings and money market accounts, CDs, bonds and bond funds, government savings bonds and T-bills, stocks, mutual funds, and IRA and Keogh accounts.

Conducting an analysis of portfolio decisions requires that one specify the set of assets from which the investor chooses. In practice, some arbitrariness is involved in aggregating financial assets into relatively homogeneous groups that are suitable for statistical analysis. A typical strategy is to collapse financial assets into three classes, "safe", "medium risky", and "risky" (Hurd, 2002), although some studies construct as many as eight to ten categories ( Poterba and Samwick, 2003). We use a four-way classification scheme consisting of safe assets (checking and savings accounts, money market funds, CDs, government savings bonds, and T-bills), bonds (corporate, municipal and foreign bonds, and bond funds), risky assets (stocks and mutual funds), and retirement accounts (IRAs and Keoghs). This is quite similar to Hurd's (2002) approach, except that he combines retirement accounts and bonds into one category. However, given the special tax treatment of IRA and Keogh accounts, and the fact that they may be relatively illiquid for some households, it seems sensible to segregate them (as do Poterba and Samwick (1999) and King and Leape (1998)). Unfortunately, the HRS does not indicate what kinds of assets are in the retirement accounts. The Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) does provide some information. On the basis of SCF tabulations, we allocate each household's retirement accounts to stocks and bonds. Doing so does not change the substantive results of our analysis of portfolio shares. , 2

Table 1 presents summary statistics of the key variables, including demographic characteristics and financial wealth holdings. The average age (over the four-year panel) of husbands is roughly 60 years and the average age of wives is 56, while singles are 59 years of age on average. Females make up 58% of single people and African-Americans make up 18%. For married couples, 3, approximately 6% of husbands and wives are black. Single people have slightly over $38,000 in financial assets on average. The figure for couples is about $95,000.

Table 1. Summary statistics for the analysis sampleData source is Waves 1–4 of the HRS. Safe assets include checking, saving and money market accounts, CDs, government savings bonds, and T-bills. Retirement accounts include IRA and Keogh accounts. Bonds include all corporate, municipal and foreign bonds, and bond funds. Risky assets include individual stocks and mutual funds. Financial assets are the sum of safe assets, retirement accounts, bonds, and risky assets. Total net worth includes all housing and non-housing equity in addition to financial assets. An individual is classified as "sick" if (s)he reports being in fair or poor health. Means are calculated using household weights provided in the HRS.

Approximately 67% of singles and 80% of married couples have a positive amount of safe asset holdings. It is not quite clear how to interpret this figure, particularly because virtually everyone in this sample presumably has Social Security wealth, which is generally perceived a safe asset. Hence, we do not include safe assets in our discussion of ownership probabilities in Section 4. The percentages for the other categories are much lower. Only 20% of singles own any risky assets, while 33% of married couples have a positive amount of these assets. The analogous numbers for bonds are only 4% and 7%. The figures in this table are consistent with previous findings that many households have incomplete portfolios in the sense that they do not own positive amounts of every type of asset. Conditional on having financial wealth, the great majority of it is held in safe assets. Safe wealth makes up an average of 64% for singles and 54% for couples. , 4

One important issue in studying portfolio shares is how broadly the measure of wealth in the denominator should be defined. Different pictures can emerge if one uses financial assets, all physical assets (including homes and automobiles), or physical assets plus human capital as the relevant measure of wealth (Heaton and Lucas, 2000). We follow most previous investigators in looking at shares of financial assets and we compute portfolio shares for all individuals who report positive financial assets. , 5

Our health status variable is based on the answer to the following question: "Would you say your health in general is excellent, very good, good, fair, or poor?" The HRS codes the answers to this question on a 1–5 scale, with 1 representing excellent health and 5 representing poor health. We create a dichotomous variable Sick, which takes a value of one if the individual rates his or her health as "fair" or "poor" and zero otherwise., 6 A large literature documents the validity of self-reported health measures. Poor self-reported health is strongly correlated with mortality even after controlling for indices of functional capacity, the presence of specific medical conditions, and physician health assessments (Idler and Benyamini, 1997). , 7 Hurd and McGarry (1995) provide additional evidence along these lines. They find correlations in the AHEAD data between self-reported health status and both mortality and the onset of several serious health conditions, after controlling for various socio-demographic conditions. , 8 That said, in the psychology literature some argue that an individual's subjective health evaluations can be distorted by mood (Schmidt et al., 1996). We therefore also estimated our model using several alternative measures of health status, including specific medical conditions and an index of the individual's ability to conduct activities of daily living. The results were qualitatively similar to those using self-reported health status.

3.1. Some cross tabulations

We begin our exploration of the relationship between health and portfolio decisions by showing how the proportion of households owning various assets and their respective portfolio shares vary with health status (Table 2). Results are shown separately for single and married people. For both individuals and couples, being healthy increases the probability of owning each one of the financial assets. For example, 25.1% of healthy single people own some risky assets. For sick single people the analogous number is only 8.2%. Similarly, 38.5% of couples in which both spouses are healthy own some risky assets. The figure is only 12.2% for couples in which both spouses are sick. The right-hand side of Table 2 indicates that health status is also correlated with the proportion of financial wealth held in each asset category. Married couples with two healthy spouses hold an average of 49.5% of their financial wealth in safe assets and 18.9% in risky assets, while couples with both spouses who are sick hold 74.7% in safe assets and only 6.6% in risky assets. A similar relationship between health status and portfolio shares holds for singles.

Table 2. Self-reported health status and portfolio decisionsAn individual is classified as "healthy" if (s)he reports having excellent, very good, or good health. An individual is classified as "sick" if (s)he reports having fair or poor health. Proportions held in particular asset categories are calculated only for those with positive financial wealth.

The figures in Table 2 show cross-sectional differences by health status. As noted below, our econometric identification strategy relies in part on such differences, but also on changes in health status within households over time. A substantial proportion of the population reports changes in health status from one wave of the HRS to the next. This number ranges from 15% to 17% of singles and 12% to 18% of husbands and wives.

To get a rough sense of whether the within-household behavior is qualitatively similar to the cross-sectional changes just discussed, we computed some simple difference-in-differences estimates of the impact of changes in health status on the change in the probability of owning risky assets and on the change in the share of financial wealth held in risky assets., 9

The difference in the differences was −0.5 percentage points, that is, households whose health worsened were less likely to own risky assets. Similarly, the difference-in-differences estimate in the share of risky assets was −0.2 percentage points. However, in both cases, the estimates were statistically insignificant. Thus, while these results in conjunction with those in Table 2 are suggestive of a relationship between health status and portfolio behavior, we need to move beyond simple comparisons of means to refine and sharpen the estimates. This observation is particularly cogent given that a number of variables are known to be correlated with health status and some of these could also be correlated with portfolio decisions. Hence, we now turn to a multivariate approach. We discuss ownership probabilities and portfolio shares in 4 and 5, respectively.

4. Ownership probabilities

Our goal is to determine whether variations in health status exert an independent effect on the probability that a household owns each of the four types of assets. We follow the general strategy employed in previous papers and estimate a probit model for the probability of owning each asset, including on the right-hand side our dichotomous variable for poor health and controls for total wealth,, 10 income, and other demographic characteristics. We pool together the data from the four waves of the HRS and use a random effects estimator of the parameters., 11 We also include a year effect for each wave.

4.1. Estimation issues

Two major issues must be addressed in estimating these models. The first is how to treat married couples versus singles. The typical practice of simply including an indicator variable for marital status (for example, Bertaut and Starr-McCluer, 2002) is really not suitable in our context. There are potentially interesting questions about decision making within households that are best explored if separate equations are estimated for single and married individuals. , 12 This decision is reinforced by Barber and Odean's (2001) finding that married and single people follow different stock trading strategies; their other portfolio decisions might differ as well.

The second issue relates to the treatment of health status for married couples. Because of different life expectancies, husbands and wives can have different time horizons. Further, there is some evidence that men and women differ with respect to risk aversion (Barber and Odean, 2001; Lott and Kenny, 1999). These considerations suggest that men and women favor different portfolio strategies and that the impact on the family's portfolio when one or the other is ill differs. Hence, there is no reason to expect health effects for the two spouses to be symmetric, so an average or combined measure is inappropriate. Instead, we enter one indicator variable for the husband's health status and another for the wife's. , 13

With respect to other covariates, our choices are quite conventional. We include age because risk aversion and the time horizon vary with it (Bertaut and Starr-McCluer, 2002, p. 199). , 14 Previous studies indicate that education exerts an important influence on portfolio choice. In general, households with more education are more likely to hold diversified portfolios, perhaps because they have better information about various investment opportunities (King and Leape, 1998, p. 190). We include a set of dichotomous variables for educational attainment. We also include indicator variables for sex (in the equation for singles) and race, and the presence of any children, all of which could affect risk aversion, the decision-making time horizon, and bequest motives.

Theory suggests that the level of total wealth is an important determinant of portfolio allocation both because it can influence risk aversion and because of fixed costs to owning certain assets (Hurd, 2002, p. 467). To allow for nonlinearities in the impact of wealth, we enter it as a quadratic. Our wealth variable includes financial wealth in addition to physical capital such as net equity in housing and businesses. Following the tack suggested by some earlier studies, we experiment with a wealth variable that also included an estimate of individuals’ human capital. , 15 This modification of the wealth variable had no impact on the estimates of health effects that are reported below. Finally, previous research has also shown that income is a significant determinant of portfolio composition even conditional on wealth (King and Leape, 1998), and we also enter it as a quadratic. , 16

4.2. Basic results

The probit estimates for single individuals and couples are reported in panels A and B of Table 3, respectively. The first column for each asset category gives the results for the basic specification. The second column for each category adds controls for parents’ education and industry and occupation., 17

Table 3. Probit models for ownership probabilitiesThe dependent variable is the probability of owning particular types of assets. Estimation is by random effects. Due to missing information on family background, industry, and occupation, sample sizes differ between first and second columns of each regression. For bonds, the regression in the second column only includes parents’ education in order to preserve a sufficient number of observations. Standard errors are in parentheses. Coefficients significant at the 5% level or better are in bold.

Consider first the health effects for the single individuals in panel A of Table 3. The results are quite striking. Being in poor health exerts a negative and statistically significant effect on the probability of owning each financial asset. , 18 Further, calculating the marginal effects from the probit coefficients listed in the table (Maddala, 1983, p. 23), we find that the effects are quantitatively important. Specifically, the figures in the first columns under each of the assets imply that being in ill health reduces the probabilities of owning retirement accounts, bonds, and risky assets by 2.1, 0.2, and 1.7 percentage points, respectively. In short, the basic message from the cross tabulations in Table 2 continues to hold when we include other covariates: health affects asset choice.

An important question is whether the observed relationship between health and portfolio choice is somehow spurious. One way this might occur is if there is reverse causality—portfolio composition affects health rather than vice versa. We find this scenario implausible. Although the notion that there are dual pathways relating health status and wealth is taken seriously in the literature (Smith, 1999), we can think of no compelling reason to believe that the allocation of that wealth to various assets would influence health status after controlling for the level of total wealth.

Another possibility is that some third variable drives both health status and portfolio choice. This seems a more substantial issue. Suppose, for example, that people with privileged family backgrounds learn more as children about the financial world and also acquire good health habits. In this case, the strength of the relationship between poor health and portfolio choice would be overestimated. Or perhaps certain jobs have more volatile income streams than others and at the same time involve more stress and worse working conditions than other jobs. Again, our estimated relationship between health status and portfolio choice would be biased. The HRS data provide us with some information that can be used to explore these possibilities. Although there is not extensive information on family background, we do know the parents’ education. Further, household members’ occupation and industry are reported. The second columns for each asset category in panels A and B of Table 3 show the results when the basic equations are augmented with parents’ education and a set of industry and occupation dichotomous variables. Although there are some systematic relationships among occupation, industry and portfolio decisions (results not shown here), the magnitude and the significance of the health effects do not change substantially. Thus, to the extent that our data allow us to explore the possible influence of third variables, we find that they do not undermine our basic finding that health status affects asset choice.

Consider next the married couples in Table 3b. There are two health coefficients for each family, one each for the husband and the wife. As in panel A of Table 3, the first column for each asset does not include controls for family background and occupational history, while the second column for each asset does. For virtually every asset type, the coefficient on poor health (of either spouse) is negative. The coefficients in the first columns of panel B of Table 3 imply that poor health of a husband reduces the likelihood of owning retirement accounts and risky assets by 8.9 and 3.0 percentage points, respectively, and has essentially no effect on the probability of owning bonds. For wives, poor health decreases the likelihood of owning retirement accounts, bonds and risky assets by 6.5, 0.2, and 4.0 percentage points. Thus, just as for singles, poor health reduces the probability of owning each financial asset, ceteris paribus. Once again, including additional controls for parents’ education, industry, and occupation does not alter substantially the magnitude or significance of the health effects.

Computations based on the coefficients in panel B of Table 3 suggest that a couple in which both spouses are in poor health is 7 percentage points less likely to hold risky assets than a couple in which both spouses are in good health, other things being the same. A natural question in this context is whether the cumulative impact when both spouses are ill is different from the sum of the individual effects. To investigate this issue, we augment each equation with an interaction between the husband's and wife's health variables. It turns out that these interactions are not significant for any of the assets (results not shown here), so that the joint effect when both spouses are in poor health is approximately equal to the sum of the individual spouses’ effects.

We now discuss very briefly the coefficients on the other variables in panels A and B of Table 3. The findings are broadly consistent with those from previous studies. For example, the probability of owning each asset tends to increase with wealth and income; the probability of owning each asset increases with age; the probability of owning risky assets increases substantially with education; and African-Americans are much less likely to own risky assets than non-African-Americans. Single females are less likely to hold risky assets and retirement funds than single males, though there are no significant gender differences for the other assets. In results not reported here, we allow the health effects of singles to vary by gender by including an interaction between sex and health status. However, this interaction term is not significant for any of the assets.

4.3. Mechanisms for health effects

Taken together, panels A and B of Table 3 indicate that health status exerts important effects on portfolio choice. For both single and married households, poor health is associated with a lower probability of owning each financial asset. As noted in the introduction, there are various mechanisms through which health might affect portfolio choice. In this section we examine several of these mechanisms.

4.3.1. Risk aversion

As already noted, theory suggests that an investor's risk aversion is an important determinant of portfolio allocation. Respondents who become sick may become less (or possibly more) risk averse than previously. The HRS asks respondents a question that is designed to provide information about their attitudes toward risk. The question asks whether they would take a job that would double their income with a 50% chance and cut it in half with a 50% chance. To investigate whether health effects might operate through impacts on risk aversion, we define the dichotomous variable risk taker, which takes the value of one if the individual answers affirmatively to the question, and zero otherwise. The results when we augment our basic model with this variable are in the first sections of panels A and B of Table 4. (This question is asked only in the first wave of the survey, so only data from that year are used to estimate this variant of the model. The same applies to the questions relating to planning horizon and bequest motives discussed below.) The results indicate that risk-loving individuals are more likely to have risky assets (although not all the point estimates are statistically significant). While this finding is perfectly intuitive, including this self-reported risk aversion measure does not affect the estimated health coefficients substantially, for either singles or married couples., 19 Hence, health does not appear to affect portfolio choices by affecting attitudes toward risk.

Table 4. Probit models for ownership probabilities using alternative specificationsThe dependent variable is the probability of owning particular types of assets. The models that include health insurance information are random-effects probits using four waves of data and including time effects, while all other models are cross-section regressions using wave 1 data (since these questions are not asked in other waves). Omitted category for planning horizon is a few months. Omitted category for bequest motive is definitely not. Standard errors are in parentheses. Coefficients significant at the 5% level or better are in bold.

4.3.2. Planning horizon

The HRS asks, "In deciding how much of their (family) income to spend or save, people are likely to think about different financial planning periods. In planning your (family's) saving and spending, which of the time periods listed …is most important to you [and your (husband/wife…)]?" The possible responses are: "next few months," "next year," "next few years," "next 5–10 years," and "more than 10 years". We create the dichotomous variable plan1 which takes a value of one if the first response was given and zero otherwise, plan2 if the second response was given, and so on. If poor health affects portfolio choices by changing people's time horizons, then when we include these dichotomous variables, the health coefficient should become less important. The second sections of panels A and B of Table 4 show the results when we augment the original specifications with the plan variables. The results indicate that households with longer time horizons are more likely to have some of each type of asset, although the relationship is not monotonic. However, including these variables in the model does not materially affect the health coefficients. Thus, there is little evidence that the results are driven by the fact that some households are more forward-looking than others.

The notion that planning horizons might be related to health raises the issue of life expectancy. The portfolios of unhealthy and healthy people can differ because unhealthy people do not expect to live as long. The HRS asks respondents to rate their chances of living to the age of 85 on a scale of one to ten. In results not reported here, we included this variable in our basic models, and found that one's perceived chance of living to 85 is not strongly related to asset allocation. Further, the health effects are about the same as in the basic model., 20

4.3.3. Bequest motives

In the same spirit, if an individual has a bequest motive, this can, in effect, extend the individual's time horizon. The HRS asks individuals whether they intend to leave a sizable bequest to their heirs. The five possible answers to this question are definitely, probably, possibly, probably not, and definitely not. We create a set of dichotomous variables on the basis of the responses and include it in the model. As indicated in the third sections of panels A and B of Table 4, the strength of the bequest motive is significantly related to the probability of ownership of financial assets, but it has no substantive impact on the coefficients on the health variables.

4.3.4. Health insurance

Another possibility is that bad health leads to large medical expenses, which induce changes in the portfolio. If this were the case, we would expect the impact of health to depend on health insurance status. To investigate this possibility, we create a dichotomous variable taking a value of one if the household is insured and zero otherwise, and we included it in the basic models. The results, reported in the fourth sections of panels A and B of Table 4, provide little evidence that the relationship between health and portfolio choice depends on the availability of health insurance. In the same spirit, we augment the basic models with out-of-pocket medical expenditures (including prescription drug payments). In results not reported here, again we find no effect on the portfolio.

4.3.5. Discussion

We examine a number of possible channels through which health can affect portfolio decisions. None of these channels do a very good job at explaining the strong relationship between health and the probability of owning particular classes of assets. One possibility is that the various attitudinal measures are not good proxies for individuals’ true underlying risk preferences, planning horizons, or bequest motives. Alternatively, some entirely different mechanisms could be at work. For example, health status can affect expectations of future income and hence permanent income, which in turn influences investment decisions. This observation is potentially troubling because to the extent wealth is measured with error, health could simply be a proxy for unobserved wealth. While our data do not allow us to investigate this possibility directly, when we estimate our basic models leaving out wealth altogether, we find that the health effects are similar both in magnitude and statistical significance. This implies that our estimated health effect is not merely an artifact of the correlation between health and wealth. We believe that this observation, together with the results in Table 4 and our discussion of "third variables" in Table 3, goes a long way in establishing that there is a robust relationship between health status and portfolio choice, though the channels through which it operates are not entirely clear.

5. Portfolio shares

5.1. Estimation issues

Our next step is to estimate how the shares of the four asset categories that comprise financial wealth depend on health status. The main statistical issue arises from the fact that portfolio shares are bounded by zero and one. Investigators use a variety of econometric approaches. Heaton and Lucas (2000) discard from their sample individuals whose stock holdings fall below a certain floor and use ordinary least squares estimation. Bertaut and Starr-McCluer (2002) utilize Heckman's (1979) selectivity bias correction to account for the fact that many of the portfolio shares are zeroes. Poterba and Samwick (2003) and Edwards (2002) use a tobit estimator. While each approach has its advantages and disadvantages, we choose the tobit model with truncation at zero. , 21 As before, we pool data from the four waves and estimate the model using random effects, including a year effect for each wave.

It is difficult to find a compelling reason to use a set of covariates different from that in the ownership equations so, following the usual practice, we use the same variables as in Table 3. A technical point arises in this context. When a set of share equations with the same right hand variables is estimated by ordinary least squares, the predicted shares are constrained to add to one, implying that the predicted marginal effects for any given covariate are constrained to sum to zero. The tobit estimator does not automatically impose this constraint. While it is possible to constrain the coefficients in this way, the process is cumbersome. , 22 It turns out that, as a practical matter, in our data the implied marginal effects come close to summing to zero, so we simply present unconstrained estimates., 23

5.2. Basic results

Following the tack we took with the ownership probabilities, we estimate the share equations separately for singles and married couples. The tobit results are presented in panels A and B of Table 5, respectively. Once again, the first column for each asset is the canonical specification and the second column includes controls for occupational history and parents’ education. Consider first the health effects for the single individuals. The results indicate that poor health increases the proportion of financial wealth held in safe assets and decreases the proportion held in the other three asset categories. Using the coefficients in the tables, we can compute the marginal effects of poor health on portfolio shares. The specifications in the first columns imply that poor health is associated with an increase of 0.042 in the proportion held in safe assets, a decrease of 0.045 held in retirement accounts, a decrease of 0.011 held in bonds, and a decrease of 0.022 held in risky assets., 24 The addition of more control variables in the second columns does not alter these results.

Table 5. Tobit regressions of portfolio sharesThe dependent variable is the share of financial wealth held in a particular asset. Due to missing information on family background, industry, and occupation, sample sizes differ between first and second columns. Tobit regressions are left-censored at zero. Standard errors are in parentheses. Coefficients significant at the 5% level or better are in bold.

The health effects for married couples are shown in panel B of Table 5. Once again, poor health for both husbands and wives leads to a higher concentration of safe assets and a lower concentration of virtually all of the other asset categories (the coefficient on husbands’ poor health in the equation for bonds is positive but insignificant). Calculations of the marginal effects for the basic specifications indicate that poor health of a husband is associated with an increase of 0.032 in the proportion held in safe assets, a decrease of 0.030 held in retirement accounts, an increase of 0.003 held in bonds and a decrease of 0.01 held in risky assets. The analogous numbers associated with a wife being in poor health are 0.029, −0.014, −0.007, and −0.021. In the second set of columns where we include controls for parents’ education, industry and occupation, the results are similar. The basic conclusion is that health is a strong predictor of how a household allocates its financial wealth to different types of assets. Specifically, poor health is associated with less risky portfolios.

5.3. Mechanisms for health effects

As in the case of ownership probabilities, we next explore possible channels through which health affects portfolio shares. Following the approach in Table 4a and b, we incorporate risk preferences, planning horizon, bequest motives, and health insurance into the basic model. The results are presented in panels A and B of Table 6 for singles and couples, respectively. Panel A of Table 6 shows that, in some cases, the additional variables are systematically related to the allocation of financial wealth. For example, from the first panel, individuals who say that they would be willing to take a job with riskier wages hold larger shares of their portfolios in risky assets and smaller shares in safe assets. Likewise, those with longer planning horizons tend to devote a smaller share of their portfolios to safe assets and a larger share in all other types of assets. Importantly, however, the inclusion of none of these variables significantly alters the coefficients on the health status variable. , 25 The results for married couples in panel B of Table 6 are similar. Hence, as is the case for ownership probabilities, none of these variables sheds much light on the channels through which health affects portfolio shares. However, an intriguing hypothesis is suggested by the theoretical model of Bodie, Merton, and Samuelson (BMS) (1992), which posits that individuals vary their labor supply to compensate for the variability in investment returns. BMS (1992) view this as an explanation for the fact that older people tend to hold safer portfolios—the ability to compensate ex post for low returns decreases with age. But when an individual is sick, his or her ability to adjust labor supply is similarly diminished. The BMS logic suggests that this, too, should induce a movement toward safer assets, just as our empirical findings suggest.

Table 6. Tobit regressions of portfolio shares using alternative specificationsThe dependent variable is the share of financial wealth held in a particular asset. Tobit regressions are left-censored at zero. Omitted category for planning horizon is next few months. Omitted category for bequest motive is "definitely not". Standard errors are in parentheses. Coefficients significant at the 5% level or better are in bold.

6. Summary and conclusions

This paper shows the existence of a strong relationship between health status and portfolio decisions. Even after controlling for the level of total net worth, household income, and a variety of socio-demographic characteristics, poor health decreases the probabilities of owning retirement accounts, bonds, and risky assets. Further, those in poor health tend to have relatively safe portfolios. Compared to households that are in good health, those in poor health hold a higher proportion of wealth in safe assets, while the proportion held in all other asset categories is lower. We find no evidence that the health effects are driven by some third variable that simultaneously influences both health status and financial decision-making.

Although the results suggest that health is an important determinant of portfolio allocation, it is not clear through what channels the effect operates. We explore several possibilities, including risk preferences, bequest motives, planning horizons, and health insurance. However, the inclusion of such variables has very little impact on the magnitude of the health effect. Perhaps the survey responses do not adequately represent individuals’ underlying attitudes, or there are other reasons why health affects household portfolio decisions. Exploring alternative mechanisms through which health might affect portfolio choice is an important avenue for future research. We view the notion that poor health reduces the household's ability to increase labor supply to compensate for bad portfolio performance as particularly promising in this context. In any case, the results in this paper suggest that there are potentially important linkages between the health care sector and financial markets. One can imagine, for example, that improvements in medical technology that improve health status will induce changes in portfolio holdings. This observation could be particularly relevant in assessing the financial consequences of the aging of the baby boomers.



References

Barber, B.M. and Odean, T., 2001. Boys will be boys: gender, overconfidence, and common stock investment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116, pp. 261–292. Abstract-EconLit   | Full Text via CrossRef

Bertaut, C.C. and Starr-McCluer, M., 2002. Household portfolios in the United States. In: Guiso, L., Haliassos, M. and Jappelli, T., Editors, 2002. Household Portfolios, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pp. 181–218.

Bodie, Z., Merton, R.C. and Samuelson, W.F., 1992. Labor supply flexibility and portfolio choice in a life cycle model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 16, pp. 427–449. Abstract | Abstract + References | PDF (1507 K)

Browning, M., 2000. The saving behavior of a two-person household. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 102, pp. 235–251. Abstract-EconLit  

Carroll, C., 2002. Portfolio of the rich. In: Guiso, L., Haliassos, M., Jappelli, T. (Eds.), Household Portfolios. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pp. 389–430.

Edwards, R.D., 2002. Health risk and portfolio choice, Unpublished working paper, University of California, Berkeley.

Foldes, L., 2000. Valuation and martingale properties of shadow prices: an exposition. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 24, pp. 1641–1701. Abstract | PDF (401 K) | MathSciNet

Gollier, C., 2002. What does theory have to say about household portfolios?. In: Guiso, L., Haliassos, M. and Jappelli, T., Editors, 2002. Household Portfolios, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pp. 27–54.

Guiso, L., Haliassos, M. and Jappelli, T., 2002. Introduction. In: Guiso, L., Haliassos, M. and Jappelli, T., Editors, 2002. Household Portfolios, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pp. 1–24.

Heaton, J., Lucas, D., 1997. Savings behavior and portfolio choice: evidence from the tax data. Unpublished working paper, Northwestern University.

Heaton, J. and Lucas, D., 2000. Portfolio choice and asset prices: the importance of entrepreneurial risk. Journal of Finance 55, pp. 1163–1198. Abstract-EconLit  

Heckman, J.J., 1979. Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica 47, pp. 153–161. Abstract-EconLit   | MathSciNet

Hurd, M.D., 2002. Portfolio holdings of the elderly. In: Guiso, L., Haliassos, M. and Jappelli, T., Editors, 2002. Household Portfolios, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pp. 431–472.

Hurd, M. and McGarry, K., 1995. Evaluation of the subjective probabilities of survival in the health and retirement survey. Journal of Human Resources 30, pp. S268–292.

Idler, E. and Benyamini, Y., 1997. Self-related health and mortality: a review of twenty-seven community studies. Journal of Health and Social Behavior 38, pp. 21–37. Abstract-MEDLINE  

King, M.A. and Leape, J.I., 1998. Wealth and portfolio composition: theory and evidence. Journal of Public Economics 69, pp. 155–193. SummaryPlus | Full Text + Links | PDF (327 K)

Lott, J.R. and Kenny, L.W., 1999. Did women's suffrage change the size and scope of government?. Journal of Political Economy 107, pp. 1163–1198. Abstract-GEOBASE | Abstract-EconLit  

Maddala, G.S., 1983. Limited-Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Econometrics, Cambridge University Press, New York.

Mazzocco, M., 2002. Savings, risk sharing and preferences for risk. Unpublished working paper, University of Wisconsin.

Mossin, J., 1968. Taxation and risk taking: an expected utility approach. Economica 35, pp. 74–82.

Poterba, J.M., 1994. Government saving incentives in the United States. In: Poterba, J.M., Editor, , 1994. Public Policies and Household Saving, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp. 1–18.

Poterba, J.M., 2001. Taxation and portfolio structure: issues and implications. NBER working paper 8223.

Poterba, J.M. and Samwick, A.A., 2003. Taxation and household portfolio composition: U.S. evidence from the 1980's and 1990's. Journal of Public Economics 87, pp. 5–38. SummaryPlus | Full Text + Links | PDF (205 K)

Schmidt, N.B., Telch, M.J. and Joiner, T.E., 1996. Factors influencing health perceptions in patients with panic disorder. Comprehensive Psychiatry 37, pp. 253–260. SummaryPlus | Full Text + Links | PDF (708 K)

Smith, J.P., 1999. Healthy bodies and thick wallets: the dual relation between health and economic status. Journal of Economic Perspectives 13, pp. 145–166. Abstract-EconLit  

Tobin, J., 1958. Liquidity preference as behavior toward risk. Review of Economic Studies 25, pp. 65–86.

Venti, S.F., Wise, D.A., 2000. Choice, chance, and wealth dispersion at retirement. NBER Working Paper 7521.

Wu, S., 2003. The effects of health events on the economic status of married couples. Journal of Human Resources 38, pp. 219–230. Abstract-GEOBASE | Abstract-EconLit  



Corresponding author. Tel.: +1-315-859-4645; fax: +1-315-859-4477

*1 We wish to thank Princeton's Center for Economic Policy Studies for financial support and to Bo Honoré, Burt Malkiel, Jonathan Meer, Ann Owen, James Poterba, Kent Smetters, an anonymous referee, and participants in seminars at Brigham Young, Northwestern, and Princeton Universities for useful suggestions.



1 See Gollier (2002) for an excellent survey.

2 We thank Andrew Samwick for providing us with the relevant calculations.

3 There are a few nonmarried cohabiters whom we include in this category. Excluding these households has no effect on our results.

4 The finding that a substantial number of US households have no safe assets (or no financial assets whatsoever) is shown in a number of data sets. See, for example, Bertaut and Starr-McCluer's (2002, p. 190) tabulations from the Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF). When a household reports not having even a checking account, the SCF asks why. Typically, such households reply that the fees are too high, they do not write enough checks to make it worthwhile, and so on.

5 Some researchers exclude households whose financial net worth does not exceed some threshold (Heaton and Lucas, 2000).

6 Analysis using all five indicator variables does not change our substantive results.

7 An alternative approach suggested by Edwards (2002) is to focus on the individual's expectation that, over a period of time such as a decade, health will interfere with ability to work. However, this limits the sample since the variable is defined only for individuals who are in the labor force at the time the question is asked.

8 As an alternative way to investigate this issue, we include an indicator for the individual's mental health status as a covariate in our basic model. If mental health is driving both self-reported health status and financial decisions, then inclusion of mental health should reduce the impact of self-reported health status. However, such does not appear to be the case in our data.

9 Specifically, using only the sample of households who experienced changes in health status, we compute the change in the proportion holding risky assets for those whose health got worse and subtracted from it the change in the proportion holding risky assets for those whose health improved. We use an analogous procedure to compute the difference-in-differences estimator for the effect of changes in health on the share of financial assets held in risky assets.

10 Total wealth includes the value of all net housing equity, all vehicles, net business equity, financial assets, and other assets including real estate. It does not include pension or social security wealth. However, when the wealth variable is augmented with an imputation for pension wealth, none of the substantive results changes.

11 With a random effects estimator, identification of the health status coefficients comes in part from changes in health status within households over time.

12 Browning (2000) and Mazzocco (2002) provide discussions of savings behavior in households with more than one decision maker.

13 As noted below, we also allowed for the possibility of an interaction between the spouses’ health outcomes and found that, in general, it had no impact on the substantive results.

14 There is a well-documented negative correlation between health status and age. This raises the possibility that the failure to include health status in analyses of portfolio choice may bias estimates of age effects. However, when we estimated our models without health, the coefficients on the age variables generally did not change substantially.

15 We follow Heaton and Lucas's (2000) algorithm for estimating human capital: Assume that for individuals under the age of 65, real labor income remains constant at its current level until age 65 and then ceases. For individuals over 65 who report labor income, assume that this income remains constant until age 70 and then ceases. Streams of labor income are discounted back to the respondent's current age at a real interest rate of 5%.

16 The results are essentially unchanged when we use step functions for wealth and household income.

17 There are 12 industry categories and 17 occupations, based on standard census classifications.

18 This is similar to Edwards’ (2002) result that poor health reduces the likelihood of stock ownership. Edwards estimates his model treating the HRS waves as a series of independent cross sections.

19 Because these models are estimated using only the first year of the panel, the results are not directly comparable to those in Table 3a. Our assessment that the health coefficients do not change much is based on a comparison to the canonical model estimated using only the first wave, which is not reported here to conserve space.

20 A person's subjective probability of living a long time can depend on how optimistic he or she is. This raises the possibility that our results are driven by the fact that optimistic people buy risky assets and say they feel healthy. The HRS does ask respondents some questions that indirectly relate to their degree of optimism. In particular, the individuals were asked to rate the likelihood that the following would occur during the remainder of their lifetimes: double-digit inflation, major depression, Social Security becoming less generous, and housing prices rising faster than inflation. These variables had no impact on portfolio composition or the coefficient on health. To the extent that these expectational variables proxy for optimism, this suggests that optimism is not driving our results.

21 Poterba and Samwick (1999) and Edwards (2002) employ a two-limit tobit estimator, with truncation at zero and one. However, in our data, none of the assets has a substantial concentration of the portfolio shares at unity, so we use the simpler one-limit version.

22 Poterba and Samwick (1999) provide further details. Note that Heckman's two-step procedure does not constrain the predicted shares to equal one.

23 Specifically, the sum of the marginal health effects comes out to −0.034 for singles, −0.005 for married men and −0.013 for married women.

24 As discussed earlier, the tobit estimator does not constrain the shares to sum to one, which explains the fact that the marginal effects do not sum to zero.

25 Recall that the models with risk preferences, planning horizons, and bequests are estimated only for the first wave, so that the health coefficients are not directly comparable to those in Table 5a and b.

 

posted on 2005-11-11 00:16 benchensz 阅读(1404) 评论(1)  编辑  收藏 所属分类: 随便写写(比较有用,值得看看)

评论

# re: 投资组合和财富(最近的阅读论文)  回复  更多评论   

e文的...........
我推荐一些z文的:http://www.utao.cn/data/ebooks/
2006-07-16 00:14 | xuweicong

只有注册用户登录后才能发表评论。


网站导航: